Skip to main content

VC Due Diligence: The Audit of P and S

This is a continuation on my post about David Silver's The VC Due Diligence Process and builds on The 3 Laws of Venture Capital. Both are commentaries of A. David Silver's book Venture Capital: The Complete Guide for Investors. The first of five audits that VC's should do when reviewing investment opportunities is the audit of the problem and solution.

Estimating the Problem Size
The first step in evaluating the problem is to estimate the total size of the problem and then the expected market share once the market has been saturated with competitors. According to Silver, the maximum plausible market share is on the order of 10 - 15%. If the goal is to have $100M+ revenues after 5 to 10 years once the market has developed, the total market size must be at least $1B. There are many methods of estimating market size, so I'll defer on the best method. But an important step in this process is to actually talk to potential customers to gauge whether they perceive the problem the same way and if they would buy a solution to solve the problem. The target here should be to validate the market size and that the market will indeed develop over time.

Characteristics of Attractive Markets
In addition to market size, Silver outlines eight factors that make a market attractive for a VC. He refers to the factors as "Demonstrable Economic Justification". The factors are:
  1. Existence of qualified buyers
  2. Existence of competent sellers
  3. Homogeneity of buyers
  4. Large number of buyers
  5. Lack of institutional barriers to selling
  6. Word-of-mouth is principal form of advertising
  7. Optimum price/cost relationship
  8. Invisibility of the new company can be maintained

1. Existence of qualified buyers
Potential buyers need to be aware of the problem, interested in it, and have the ability to pay for the solution. If the buyers are not yet aware of the problem (or have a very different perception of it), the entrpreneur will have to spend millions of dollars educating them on it before they sell them the solution. VC's generally don't want to invest in companies that have to create the demand curve from scratch.

2. Existence of competent sellers
Even if there are qualified buyers, the entrepreneur needs a competent and qualified sales and marketing team that connects with the specific buyers in that market. Sales people should be competitive and have operated at a high-level in a competitive environment. Some VC's prefer a three-person start-up team including the "people, pencil, and paper". "People" is the entrepreneur that has the vision for marketing and selling the product. "Pencil" is the manager partner, the person that can make sure things get done right. "Paper" is the finance and administrative perspective, the person that can often be the "nay-sayer".

3. Homogeneity of buyers
Often, entrepreneurs have found a solution that can be applied to numerous problems. The entrepreneur needs to focus on those problems that have a market with the most similar buyers. The market with the most homogenous buyers is the most efficient to address. It is capital intensive to customize your product for multiple markets, problems, and buyer types, which ultimately limits your ability to scale.

4. Large number of buyers
You want your market to have an infinite number of buyers. Or, if there are a small number of buyers, there should either be the opportunity for repetitive sales (e.g. razor-blade model) and/or sales of ancillary products and services (e.g. maintenance contracts, replacement parts, etc.). In terms of how many buyers, again the benchmark is generally a $1B market with no single company attaining more than 10 or 15% market share. The other assumption that Silver asserts is that "anything worth doing will be copied by others who have substantial and excellent management".

Silver also described by niches are not attractive to VC's. To address a niche and launch a product, a VC would likely end up with greater than a 50% equity ownership in a company. There's no equity remaining if the entrepreneur wants to launch a follow-up product. The economics just don't work for VC's.

5. Lack of institutional barriers to selling
Associations in any industry are often setup to (paradoxically) prevent the introduction of solutions to problems that the industry faces. Why would they do so? Because associations are "don't rock the boat" oriented. The current structure of industries often affords its participants high salaries and fat profit margins. New technologies can disrupt value chains and create losers. Entry into markets with institutional barriers is much more expensive.

6. Word-of-mouth is principal form of advertising
In a capital constrained environment, mass advertising really isn't an option. VC's like investments that require minimal amounts of money for advertising. The function of advertising is to create "solution awareness" - not to educate the market on the problem or to create a demand curve. The demand should already be there. VC's want to invest in products and services that 1) have customers that will say it works, and 2) where others will believe those customers and then try the product as a result. A great example that Silver talks about are productivity improving capital for large corporations (e.g. most enterprise software) because sales are heavily reference-based. Books like Crossing the Chasm talk at length about the importance of reference sales, particularly from early adopters.

Two important implications of this are that industries with buyer credibility issues (i.e. where your buyers lack credibility -- e.g. drug abusers) or that require you to attack the consumer mass market are generally avoided by VC's. References and word-of-mouth advertising can't be used when the buyers aren't credible and mass markets require marketing genius, which is extremely rare.

7. Optimum price/cost relationship
The minimum gross profit margin that VC's look for is around 60%. Silver illustrates this with a discussion of the difference between Apple and Osborne Computer Corp. While Apple went with a premium pricing strategy (with 80%+ margins), Osborn went with a low-cost product with much lower margins (~47%) that included expensive hardware components as well as software. Although the company created it own challenges, the company ultimately went bankrupt in part due to sustained losses. Two important lessons for entrepreneurs from this - 1) don't underprice your product and 2) throw in add-ons (don't make everything inclusive).

Another lesson related to finances is to make cash flow projections for multiple scenarios (think Monte Carlo simulation) to ensure you have enough capital.

8. Invisibility of the new company can be maintained
This one is simple - keep a low profile until your product works. There will be many followers and imitators even if you have patent protection. VC's won't invest in entrepreneurs that have advertised before they have an ability to deliver. There's a high likelihood that someone else will beat them to market with a working solution.

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Nine Prescriptions for Building the Duke Entrepreneurial Community

I think Duke can have one of the strongest entrepreneurial communities in the world. Are we there yet? Well, not yet. But there's a tremendous amount of momentum that I saw build in just the past two years while I was getting my MBA at Duke. While leading Duke's 10th annual business plan competition, the Duke Start-Up Challenge (DSC) , last year, I witnessed a near doubling of participation on campus in just a single year. The interest on the ground was clearly there and building rapidly. But now that I'm an alum, I'm looking back and wondering ... how do we rev-up the Duke entrepreneurial community even more? I read a great article by Daniel Isenberg, a professor of management at Babson, called " How to Start an Entrepreneurial Revolution " in the June edition of the Harvard Business Review. Isenberg outlines nine prescriptions for governments that want to create entrepreneurship ecosystems in their countries. Although he was focused on governments an

Biofuels May Hinder Anitglobal-Warming Efforts

Read an interesting article a couple weeks back in the WSJ on how biofuels may actually increase carbon emissions in the medium to long-term. Apprently the shifts in land-use necessary to support the production of bio-materials like soybeans, corn, or palm could in fact release more carbon emissions. The time it takes to get carbon-neutral on some of these projects is pretty crazy - 319 years for soybean biodiesel from Brazil (assuming you're clearing rainforest), 93 years for corn ethanol from the U.S. (assuming you're clearing grasslands), 86 years for palm biodiesel from Indonesia (assuming you're clearing rainforest). I suppose biofuels really aren't meant to reduce carbon emissions, but just crazy that they potentially exacerbate the problem so much.

Bloomberg for President?

We can only hope. I read an article in the WSJ about how business people across the country, from entrepreneurs to bankers, are all hoping for Bloomberg to run. The economy thus far seems to have taken an unusual backseat in this years election but seems to be emerging as an important issue. An interesting excerpt: As the economy has emerged as a dominant issue in the 2008 campaign, candidates have struck populist notes, from Republican Mike Huckabee's boast that he is not a "wholly owned subsidiary of Wall Street" to Democrat Barack Obama's visit to Wall Street to chastise finance executives for failing to protect the middle class. I can see the approach these guys are taking and I'm sure they have really smart campaign strategists. But I really wonder if this type of message of polarizing the "working man" vs. "big business" really resonates with voters anymore? Is the middle-class really that disgruntled with big business and income dispa